Marketable Permits: Reducing Pollution, Saving The Planet

how marketable permits can reduce pollution

Marketable permits, also known as emissions trading or cap and trade, are a government-created license that regulates the level of a particular activity, such as pollution. They create a flexible system that incentivizes firms to reduce pollution and account for external costs. Firms that efficiently reduce emissions can profit by selling excess permits, while others can purchase permits to continue operating without disruptions. This promotes innovation and investment in cleaner technologies, ultimately helping governments achieve their environmental targets.

Characteristics Values
Type Government-created license
Purpose To regulate the level of a particular activity
Function Rationing the use of a resource
Flexibility Firms can choose how to reduce pollution levels
Incentive Financial gain from selling excess permits
Outcome Reduced pollution
Market Demand and supply set the price
Effect Reduced demand for pollution over time
Regulation Cap-and-trade, rate-based trading, or credit trading
Cost Administrative costs of implementing and monitoring

shunwaste

Firms can sell excess permits and buy permits to continue operating without disruptions

Marketable permits are a type of government-created license that regulates the level of a particular activity. In the context of pollution, firms are given a legal right to pollute up to a certain amount. If a firm produces less pollution, it can sell its excess permits to other firms that might need them. Conversely, if a firm exceeds its pollution limit, it can purchase additional permits from other firms or the government. This creates a market for pollution permits, with the price determined by demand and supply.

The ability to buy and sell permits allows firms to continue operating without disruptions. For example, consider a firm that has been allocated 100 units of carbon dioxide permits per year. If the firm implements new technologies or more efficient practices and reduces its carbon dioxide emissions to only 80 units per year, it can sell the remaining 20 units of permits to another firm. This way, the firm can recover some of the costs associated with implementing the new technologies or practices. On the other hand, if the firm experiences unexpected growth or changes that lead to an increase in emissions, it can purchase additional permits to ensure it remains compliant without disrupting its operations.

The market for pollution permits provides incentives for firms to reduce pollution and its associated external costs. By creating a market, the government can control the total amount of pollution by setting a cap on the number of permits available. Firms that need additional permits will have to purchase them from other firms or the government, increasing their costs. This provides a financial incentive for firms to reduce their pollution levels and invest in more efficient technologies.

The price of pollution permits is determined by the interplay between demand and supply. If there is rapid economic growth or an increase in the demand for polluting activities, the cost of permits will rise. Similarly, if the government decides to reduce the number of permits available over time, the price will increase, creating a stronger incentive for firms to reduce their pollution levels. As the demand for permits falls due to firms actively reducing pollution, the government can respond by gradually decreasing the supply of permits, leading to a decline in pollution in the long term.

Overall, the ability to sell excess permits and buy additional permits allows firms to maintain their operations while providing them with financial incentives to reduce pollution and invest in more efficient technologies over time.

shunwaste

Market-driven incentive allows for international cooperation and integration

Market-based approaches are increasingly being used to address a wide range of environmental issues, from acid rain to climate change. These approaches use business models and market forces to address development and humanitarian challenges more sustainably and/or at scale. Market-driven incentives provide continuous inducements, monetary and near-monetary, to encourage polluting entities to reduce the release of harmful pollutants.

Market-based approaches create an incentive for the private sector to incorporate pollution abatement into production or consumption decisions and to innovate in such a way as to continually search for the least costly method of abatement. As a result, firms will reduce their emissions as long as it is financially valuable for them to do so, and this generally happens at a point where marginal abatement costs are equated across all regulated firms.

Cost savings for firms also often translate into cost savings for customers who purchase products from regulated firms, resulting in lower overall social costs. Market-based approaches can also be used to address development and humanitarian challenges more sustainably and/or at scale. For example, a market-based approach could support the private sector in developing a pay-per-use model that expands sanitation infrastructure and services that underserved customers would not otherwise be able to access.

In addition, market-based approaches can build the healthcare ecosystem through technical assistance and access to finance, allowing for better provision of care through small and medium enterprises. This type of approach can also be used to address environmental issues that pose equity concerns. For instance, emissions trading programs could have the unintended consequence of concentrating pollution in economically disadvantaged areas (pollution hotspots).

Market-driven incentives allow for international cooperation and integration by altering the structure of a state's external payoffs and affecting its internal preferences and choices to induce cooperation by the recipient. According to William Long, incentives externally offer an exchange of economic gains from trade and technology transfer for political concessions. They are compelling when the sender has market power in the traded goods, both the recipient and sender stand to gain from economic relations, and the recipient's total utility for the gains from trade remains positive.

Market-driven incentives also shape state preferences in a cooperative direction by building alliances with actors in the recipient state who will benefit from the incentives. They create support for the incentives in the sending state among actors who will benefit from them. Unlike sanctions, they do not encourage the recipient state to find ways to evade the impact of the action or filter out the message behind the incentives.

shunwaste

Firms can reduce emissions at the lowest possible cost

Marketable permits are a type of government-created license that regulates the level of a particular activity. They can be used to reduce pollution by creating a market for pollution permits, with the price set by demand and supply. The aim is to provide market incentives for firms to reduce pollution and the external costs associated with it. Firms that produce less pollution can sell their permits, while those that produce more pollution must buy them. This system allows firms to reduce emissions at the lowest possible cost in the following ways:

Cap-and-Trade Programs

Regulators set a limit, or cap, on the total amount of pollution that can be emitted. Firms that are able to operate within their allotted amount of permits have the flexibility to sell their excess permits to other firms, thus reducing emissions at a lower cost.

Rate-Based Trading Programs

Agencies limit the relative amount of pollution per regulated entity or unit of regulated activity. For example, a rate-based air pollution permit market may limit the amount of pollution power plants can emit per unit of electricity generated. This encourages firms to reduce emissions without incurring high costs.

Credit Trading Systems

Regulators set a relative goal, such as no net increase in emissions, and covered entities must purchase offsetting credits if they wish to increase emissions. Credits can be earned when parties limit their pollution levels by more than the required amount. This system provides an incentive for firms to reduce emissions beyond the required amount, as they can then sell the excess credits.

Auctions

Distributing permits through auctions can reduce barriers to entry for new firms and lower the risk of monopolies and strategic behaviour. This promotes competition and can help reduce emissions at a lower cost.

Renewable Energy

Firms can reduce emissions by switching to renewable energy sources. There are an increasing number of green energy providers offering renewable energy plans, and firms can also invest in on-site renewable energy sources.

Sustainable Suppliers and Web Hosting

Firms can reduce emissions by choosing sustainable suppliers and web hosting services. This involves working with suppliers that use eco-friendly methods and technology that improves energy efficiency.

Reduce, Reuse, and Recycle

Firms can reduce emissions by implementing the three Rs: reduce, reuse, and recycle. This involves creatively applying these principles to all areas of the business, including office supplies, processes, and packaging.

Online Meetings and Events

By adopting a hybrid work model and moving to online meetings and events, firms can reduce travel-related emissions and lower their carbon footprint.

Green Office Equipment

Firms can invest in green office equipment, such as LED lighting, energy-efficient kitchen appliances, and energy-saving modes on electronic devices. Lowering the office thermostat by just 1°C can reduce energy for heating by about 13%.

shunwaste

Governments can achieve their environmental targets

Marketable permits, also known as emissions trading or "cap and trade", are a government-enforced policy that can help governments achieve their environmental targets. This is how they work:

How Marketable Permits Work

Marketable permits are a type of government-issued license that regulates the level of a particular activity, such as pollution. They create a flexible "cap and trade" system, allowing firms to buy, sell, or trade these permits. The system incentivizes firms to reduce pollution and account for external costs.

Firms that efficiently reduce emissions can profit by selling excess permits, while those that are unable to reduce emissions below the cap can purchase or trade for additional permits from more efficient firms. This provides a financial incentive for firms to account for external costs without significant disruption to their operations.

Advantages of Marketable Permits

Marketable permits have several advantages. Firstly, they promote innovation and investment in cleaner technologies. Firms are incentivized to reduce pollution and develop more sustainable practices, ultimately helping governments achieve their environmental goals.

Secondly, marketable permits allow for international cooperation and integration by providing a common framework for emission reduction efforts. This can lead to greater harmonization of environmental policies and more efficient resource allocation on a global scale.

Thirdly, marketable permits offer flexibility in meeting regulatory targets. Firms have the option to either reduce emissions or purchase permits, allowing them to choose the most cost-effective approach for their business.

Types of Marketable Permitting Programs

There are three main types of marketable permitting programs:

  • Cap-and-trade programs: Regulators set a limit, or cap, on the total amount of a regulated activity, such as the total tons of a pollutant.
  • Rate-based trading programs: Similar to cap-and-trade, but instead of capping the total amount, agencies limit the relative amount of activity per regulated entity or unit of activity.
  • Credit trading systems: Regulators set a relative goal, such as no net increase in emissions, and covered entities must purchase offsetting credits from third parties if they want to increase emissions. Credits can also be earned by parties that reduce their emissions beyond the required amount.

Considerations for Implementing Marketable Permits

When implementing marketable permits, agencies must consider several factors. These include clearly defining the privileges and obligations conveyed by the permits, ensuring a robust market is feasible, addressing compliance costs, and monitoring and enforcing compliance.

Overall, marketable permits provide a flexible and market-driven approach to reducing pollution and achieving environmental targets. By creating a market for pollution permits, governments can incentivize firms to innovate, invest in cleaner technologies, and reduce their environmental impact.

shunwaste

Firms can reduce pollution and account for external costs

Marketable permits, also known as emissions trading or "cap and trade", are a government-enforced policy that sets a limit on pollution and allows firms to trade permits. This creates a flexible system that incentivizes firms to reduce pollution and account for external costs.

Firms that efficiently reduce emissions can profit by selling excess permits, while others can purchase permits to continue operating without disruptions. This promotes innovation and investment in cleaner technologies, ultimately achieving government-established environmental targets.

The incentive for a firm to account for external costs comes from the market created by the cap and trade system. If a firm can reduce its pollution more efficiently than the market price of a permit, it may choose to do so and sell any excess permits at a profit. This provides an economic incentive for firms to innovate and invest in technologies and methods that reduce pollution.

On the other hand, if a firm is unable to reduce its pollution below the level allowed by its permits, it can purchase or trade for additional permits from other firms that have reduced their emissions below their cap. This provides a financial incentive to account for external costs without significant disruption to operations.

Overall, marketable permits provide firms with incentives to take external costs into account by creating a competitive market for pollution reduction, encouraging innovation and investment in cleaner technologies, and offering flexibility to achieve government-regulated limits.

By reframing resource conservation and allocation into a money-based framework, agencies are forced to prioritize sustainability within their practices. However, it is important to consider the potential for market manipulation and failure due to volatility, which could lead to environmental injustice.

Frequently asked questions

Marketable permits are a type of government-created license that regulates the level of a particular activity. They can be bought or sold independently of any real property or other interest.

Marketable permits create a flexible "cap and trade" system, incentivizing firms to reduce pollution and account for external costs. Firms that efficiently reduce emissions can profit by selling excess permits, while others can purchase permits to continue operating without disruptions.

Marketable permits are more cost-effective than traditional command-and-control regulations. They create a market-driven incentive for international cooperation and integration, leading to greater harmonization of environmental policies and more efficient resource allocation at a global level. They also provide flexibility in meeting regulatory targets and requirements.

Critics argue that price volatility, market power, and the potential for market manipulation can subject marketable permits to market failure, undermining their effectiveness and leading to distorted market outcomes. There is also a risk of overallocation of permits, which would lead to insufficient emission reductions and disproportionately affect lower-income populations.

Examples of marketable permit trading schemes include the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) and China's national cap-and-trade program. In 1990, the US also pursued a form of sulphur trading scheme that successfully reduced sulphur dioxide emissions by 40%.

Written by
Reviewed by
Share this post
Print
Did this article help you?

Leave a comment